The aim of World Bank under SAPs as
a contribution through liberalization was to unleash the creative forces of
private entrepreneurship within smallholder agriculture and indigenous trading
systems. The major objective of the liberalization measures was to increase
productivity in agriculture, particularly small holder activities so as to
enhance incomes and food security at both household and national levels
(Government of Zimbabwe, 1995). It was assumed that market reforms would favor
the production of tradables such as horticulture, tobacco and cotton through
affecting the relative prices of these commodities.
World Bank- plays a qualitatively different
role than the IMF, but works tightly within the stringent SAP framework imposed
by the IMF (Masanzu, et al, 1998). It focuses on development loans for specific
projects such as the building of dams, roads, harbors and among many others
that are considered necessary for ‘economic growth’ in a developing country
(ibid). Since it is a multilateral institution, the World Bank is less likely
than unilateral lending institutions such as the Export Import Bank of the US
that offer loans for the purpose of promoting and subsidizing particular
corporations (Makamure, 1996). Nevertheless, the conceptions of growth and
economic well being within the World Bank are very much molded by western
corporate values and rarely take account of local cultural concerns (ibid).
Agriculture is the backbone of
Zimbabwe’s economy so it provides employment incomes for 70 % of the
population, 60 % of the raw materials required by the industrial sector and
contributes 40 % of total export earnings (Government of Zimbabwe, 1997). The
sector directly contributes between 15 % and 19 % to annual GDP depending on
the rainfall pattern (ibid). It contributes more than 60 % of the country’s
total foreign currency earnings annually (Berman& Carter, 1997). However,
the average growth rate of agriculture since the launch of ESAP in 1991, at 1,
4 % per annum (target is 3, 2 % per annum) has been inadequate to maintain
national food supplies, to improve the incomes of small holder farmers, to meet
the basic requirements of industry and viable export markets (Mukora&
Friedrich, 1997). It is the purpose of this paper to
outline the contribution of the World Bank to Zimbabwe’s agriculture.
ESAP was born in 1991 and consisted
of a series of economic policy reforms which were to be carried out over a
five-year period. The government instituted policies that were aimed at market
deregulation, liberalization and export promotion (Makamure, 1996). In the
Second Five Year National Development Plan (1991-95) the government said its
major thrust was to enhance food self-sufficiency for the population, increase
exports, expand employment and meet the raw material requirements of the
manufacturing sector (Government of Zimbabwe, 1995). In general terms, ESAP
resulted in government cutting budgets in several ministries and instituted
measures towards curtailing losses of parastatals (Masanzu, et al, 1998). The
government reduced its intervention that had been aimed at the further development
of the agricultural sector while at the same time it pushed for export-oriented
production (production of tradables) (ibid). In its agricultural policy
statements over the years the government repeatedly pointed out that, one of
the most important problems facing Zimbabwe was to generate substantially
greater farm output from smallholder farming (communal, resettlement and small
scale farming) in order to meet direct household consumption needs and to
generate greater net farm cash incomes (Dorward, 1999).
Generally, the design of Zimbabwe’s
agricultural sector policies as part of the country’s structural adjustment
process since 1991 has been largely influenced by reduction of government’s
direct involvement in the production, distribution and marketing of
agricultural inputs and commodities (Masuko, 1999). More so, it concentrated on
removal of price subsidies on farming sub sectors, including input supply and
State-run credit schemes (ibid). At the same time promoting liberalization of
export, import trade and privatization of agricultural marketing supply/demand
balance for agricultural commodities (Berman & Carter, 1997). Contribution
of the World Bank through Liberalization of agricultural exports has assisted
the government in 1990 to start an all out export drive and designed a number
of policies to stimulate exports (ibid).
Resulting to the introduction of the
Export Retention scheme (ERS) which allowed exporters to retain a percentage of
their export earnings and also the Open General Import License (OGIL) which started
in October 1990 by putting in place agricultural inputs like stock feed, tyres
and spares (Berman & Carter, 1997). There was also the Export Revolving
Fund (ERF) which was introduced in 1983 which provided exporters with foreign
exchange for needed imports and was replaced by the Export Support Facility
(ESF) as an addition to the ERS (ibid).
The biggest export incentive
however, was the devaluation of the Zimbabwe dollar throughout the 1990s
(Makamure, 1996). As a result, agricultural producers suddenly got much higher
prices in Zimbabwe dollars for their exports and there has now been partial
liberalization of export and import trade (Mukora & Friedrich, 1997). Whilst
on the other hand, the economic reform program implicitly made an incorrect
assumption that production in the sector is homogeneous, therefore farmers in
Zimbabwe have equal opportunities to enter and gain within this capitalist liberal
market system (ibid). In order for producers to obtain higher producer prices
in a liberalized market, they will have to produce those commodities for which
they have a comparative advantage with respect to available markets (Berman
& Carter, 1997). Producers located further away from markets had to produce
high value commodities and they needed support to be able to make this
transition (ibid). By definition, market reforms favored the production of
tradables such as horticulture, tobacco and cotton through affecting the
relative prices of these commodities (Friedrich, 1997). The local prices of
these externally tradable commodities rise faster through devaluation than the
locally tradable commodities such as maize (ibid).
While to some extent this has
happened during the period of reforms, on the whole agricultural productivity
in the small-holder sector has been threatened by lack of effective marketing
systems, shortage of land, so as to lack of storage and transport facilities
(Friedrich, 1999). More so, there was an evolution of soaring inflation
especially since the start of the economic reform program in 1991, the high
cost of money, high rates of taxes and other costs eroded the viability of
farming and hit hard smallholder farmers who did enjoy economies of scale than
their large-scale counterparts (Friedrich, 1998). The removal of input subsidies
(for example fertilizer) caused a predictable crisis for smallholder and
communal farmers, yet alternatives to them were underdeveloped (ibid).
According to the Ministry of Lands
and Agriculture (1999) reported that,
the cost of producing one hectare of wheat had risen by 68,54 % between
1998 and 1999, and the direct costs of producing cotton had escalated by 120%.
The cost of stock feed had increased livestock costs of production
tremendously. For example, from the period January 1998 to January 1999, most
beef concentrates increased over 100 %, dairy concentrates over 100 %, ostrich
concentrates over 120 %,poultry and rations 72 %, pig concentrates over 76 %
and in some cases stock feed additives had increased over 200 % (Dorward, 1999).
Very few agricultural production
systems gave a return of the order of 50 % and farmers who borrowed money from
commercial finance houses to grow crops, particularly non-export commodities
were not able to benefit from devaluation, they also could not make any profit
out of the exercise (ibid). Interest rates for example, comprised largest
components of production costs. In smallholder agriculture, transport costs alone
constituted about 25 % of total costs per ton produced compared to around 12 %
in other sectors (ZFU, 1998).The high cost of credit has also hampered rural
traders from constructing warehouses for input supply, provision of trucks to
smallholder farmers to transport inputs and farm produce and the development of
smallholder irrigation schemes (ibid).
Market reforms as part of World
Bank’s contribution to the agriculture of Zimbabwe was the call for
diversification, while essential, it could not be assumed that it would just
happen (Muchena, 1995). Pre-requisites for effective diversification there is
need for irrigation development, development of adequate technology options in
the various farming regions and access to capital (ibid). More so, there is need of availability of
markets, improved farmer advisory services, stabilization of food crop
production and specialized settlement schemes (Muchena, 1995). Most of the
diversification options which are available on the market such as ostrich
production and specialized horticulture are capital intensive and the start-up
capital is far beyond the reach of many communal farmers (Oxfarm, 1995).
Options that take a long time for returns to be realized will not be taken up
by the resource starved small holder farmers (Friedrich, 1999).
To add on, the emergence of
alternative marketing channels to some area in the country were considered as a
welcome development, as it brought wider choice to farmers about where and when
to buy and sell their produce (Makamure, 1996). In the focused group
discussions conducted for this study in Chivi and Mutasa districts, farmers
confirmed a four-fold increase in the use of private marketing channels (ibid).
The study showed that the shift to private channels was in some cases attributable
to low transaction costs and early payment of produce (Mukora & Friedrich,
1997). A similar study conducted by Intermediate Technology Development Group
(ITDG) (1997) indicated that, in the case of groundnuts, sunflower and small
grains, farmers in the district (for example, Gutu) had shifted completely to
private marketing channels so as to take advantage of higher producer prices,
low transaction costs and timely payment.
Under ESAP, involvement of small traders,
transporters and other entrepreneurs was recommended but lacked policy measures
to enhance fairness and effectiveness. Following the worst drought in living
memory in 1992, the government introduced to targeted smallholders free crop
packs consisting of seeds, fertilizers, crop chemicals and contract ploughing
in order to help resource poor farmers recover and increase their productivity
(Whiteside, 1997). Since 1992, the government implemented five phases of seed,
fertilizer and transport crop pack programs even during favorable rainfall
years to ensure that smallholders achieved food security and reduced the cost
of drought relief food distribution (Mukora & Friedrich, 1997). However,
the government stopped the free crop pack program in 1997 and began to assist
smallholder farmers to set up agric-input dealer agencies which however did not
take off in earnest (ibid).
However, they were various
constraints which existed in the marketing of agricultural products like poorly
developed market information system to link farmers and buyers and lack of
guaranteed markets for smallholder produce (Dorward, 1999). Furthermore, there
was an addition of limited agribusiness dealers in rural areas and the absence
of essential rural infrastructure particularly feeder roads, irrigation facilities,
telephones, electricity and banking services (Masuko, 1999). For example, the
National Farm Irrigation Fund, which was established in 1985 to meet the
requirements of irrigation development, was used to a large extent by the
large-scale sector (ibid). More so,
inaccessibility of some emerging marketing channels to smallholder farmers and
partial liberalization of certain agricultural products (Chisvo et al 1999).
For example, The Case of Shamva
District showed that the mean district to the market was 34, 8 km for maize,
89, 8 km for tobacco, 34, 4 km for cotton, 39 km for sunflower, 100 km for
onions and 115 km for tomatoes (Masuko, 1999). Only 3, 6 % of the producers
used their own vehicles to transport crops to the market (ibid). The survey
also found out that the small holder sector showed limited response to changes
in the global markets while there was a significant shift from non-tradables to
tradables within the commercial farming sector while small holder farmers were
still concentrated in the production of the staple food crop like maize
(Mwanza, 1999). The involvement of the smallholder sector in the production of
tradables was hindered by the limited access to some factors of production
needed to produce tradables such as irrigation facilities, agricultural inputs,
access to information and financing (Munhamo, 1998).
While liberalization did bring in
more players on the market for different agricultural commodities as predicted,
this did not necessarily result in higher prices and it did not improve the
lives of rural households as anticipated (Munhamo, 1998). Some farmers (those
who had better access to factors of production) benefited from liberalization
in some ways and were able to improve their lives, whereas the majority was
actually in a worse off position than before the introduction of ESAP (ibid).
To add on, the liberalization of the
beef industry from 1991 under ESAP has led to the proliferation of private
slaughterhouses (Makumure, 1996). There are about 54 registered private
abattoirs at the moment. Despite the commission being registered as a private
company in 1995, its dominance in the beef market has declined significantly
(Muchena, 1995). Throughput to the CSC has dropped quite substantially from a
peak of 656 396 in 1977 to 137 285 in 1999 (Oxfarm, 1995). The company is now
handling between 20 and 25 % of national slaughtering. On the other hand,
registered private sector activity has increased significantly since 1981 from
42 923 head of cattle slaughtered to 204 964 in 1999 (Mwanza, 1999). In other
words, liberalization has only benefited private abattoirs (ibid). According to
beef industry experts, the biggest mistake that was made by the government was
not to make the beef industry strategic and provide enough support to producers
(Munhamo, 1998).
Impact of liberalization on
household food security, studies has found out that household food security was
worsened during liberalization (Munhamo, 1998). While Zimbabwe was generally
food secure in terms of national requirements, it is certainly that it has
experienced unacceptable levels of household hunger as evidenced by the fact
that 30 % of children under the age of five were chronically malnourished
(Makamure, 1996). Furthermore the
National food security did not guarantee household food security and food
security in Zimbabwe was only guaranteed when each and every Zimbabwean
household had access to an adequate diet necessary for a healthy and active
life, day in and day out (ibid). In
other words, the commercialization of smallholder agriculture has in practice
meant the use of bought inputs (fertilizer, hybrid seed among many others) and
an increased concentration on cash sales rather than production for home
consumption (ZFU, 1998). This has tended to encourage agricultural extension
services to provide more support to better-off smallholders and giving
exclusive grazing and water rights to better-off farmers (ZFU, 1999).
For example, a study conducted in
the Mutasa and Chivi districts by Chisvo , few households purchased maize grain
from the market because most farmers were consuming grain from their own
supplies at the time (Masuko,1999). However, maize production in recent years
has been sufficient to cover the period immediately before the next harvest.
With the rising cost of inputs, the proportion of food-deficit households
usually rises during the November to March period. The respondents preferred to
borrow or to buy grain from neighbors to replenish their depleted supplies
because of the prohibitive costs of more refined roller meal (Mukora
&Friedrich, 1997). With the implementation of ESAP, the sources of income
for rural people have become more diverse.
The main source of income for most
respondents was crop production. The poorest households said they supplemented
their income from agriculture by hiring out their labor to better-off farmers
for cash or food (Dorward, 1999). The Zimbabwe Agricultural Commodity Exchange
ZIMACE was formed in March 1994 to provide an alternative route for
agricultural marketing in line with the liberalization of agricultural markets
(ZIMACE, 1999). It operated on an open outcry system whereby bid and offer
prices were called out at each trading session and confirmed by the brokers in
attendance (ibid). This enabled market forces, particularly supply and demand,
to achieve a price agreed to on a ‘willing seller, willing
buyer’ basis. The
Exchange gained popularity among producers more and more small scale farmers
were now trading their commodities through ZIMACE who were looking for a
transparent market place with security, for legally binding contracts and for
an arbitration facility which protected both parties (Masanzu, et al, 1998).
Three main crops traded at the
exchange were maize, wheat and soya beans and there was potential to expand the
commodities traded at ZIMACE. Farmers
were generally happy with the prices offered through ZIMACE which was
strengthened over the years (Munhamo, 1998). The farmer now had the most important
commodity information at their fingertips and they were also able to look at
prices in the market place, talk to their broker, consider factors like the
probable exchange rate at harvest time and could get information on
international commodity prices (Rukuni & Eicher, 1994).
All this was vital in deciding what
crops to grow and the Gokwe Farmers Marketing Association is a good example of
small farmer participation in the exchange (ibid). The association has been
trading small volumes of maize for the last two years and about 400 tons were
traded in the 1998/99 marketing season (ZFU, 1998/99).
Milliken of Bateleur Ventures
asserted that there were still some difficulties which needed to be conquered
for more small-scale farmers to trade their commodities through ZIMACE
(Munhamo, 1998). Among these was that the small-scale farmer’s need for instant
cash payment instead of waiting the normal 14 days, and the amount of paperwork
involved when trading small parcels of maize (ibid). To facilitate the Gokwe farmers’ entry onto
ZIMACE, Bateleur provided bridging finance needed to meet the farmers’ demands
for instant payment therefore support from banks was critical (Munhamo, 1998).
With more information the exchange could provide small-scale farmers with
protection against grain buyers who offered lower prices for cash (ibid).
Formal employment in the
agricultural sector remained constant at 300,000 in the first years of ESAP
(Mwanza, 1999). However, the high inflation rate triggered by ESAP, reduced the
real value of agricultural wages such that in 1992, real wages were half their
1990 level (ZCTU, 1996). Permanent employments in the LSCF sector–particularly
tobacco and horticulture –increased by 10,000–15000, while casual labor
increased by about 30,000 (ibid). The share of wages in the value of LSCF
marketed output fell from an average of 36% over the 1980-83 periods to 35%
during the period 1988 91, and less than 15% by 1993 (ZCTU,1999). Farmers’
responses to the new SAP measures were largely conditioned by the size and
nature of their operations (ibid).
The total acreage under crop in the
communal and resettlement areas declined, while at the same time more and more
people became dependent on agriculture within the communal areas due to natural
growth of the population and ESAP-induced retrenchments (CFU, 1999). The World
Bank attributes this decline among other reasons to reduced availability of
credit, less fertilizers and agro-chemicals and the reduced availability of
seed (ibid). More so, there were also negative factors such as low rainfall
levels, expansion of cultivation into more marginal areas, declining soil
fertility and continued clearance of wood cover which resulted to erosion
(Friedrich, 1999).
While this analysis has its merits,
it however placed little emphasis on the lack of land redistribution as a key constraint
for smallholder production growth and basic cause of environmental degradation
(Nyagura, et al, 1998). Thus, the attainment of improved productivity and
higher food production among small-scale farmers, for example, remained an area
of critical concern (ibid).
According to the Ministry of Lands and
Agriculture (1999) “Policy Strategies for Stimulating Agricultural Production
and Food Security for the 1999/2000 Farming Season and Beyond” the problem of
low productivity in the small holder farming areas was a function of factors
which included poor farming skills, limited use of technical inputs,
unavailability of technical inputs owing to poor infrastructure, poor soils and
inadequate provision of extension back-up and farmer training. For example,
small holder farmers consumed 25 % of the total fertilizer in Zimbabwe and on
average apply 50 kgs of fertilizer compared to 700 kgs per hectare by
large-scale commercial farmers (Mwanza, 1999). Well-intentioned as the policy
may have been, Government did not implement complementary policies such as
information flow, market research and infrastructure development and this led
to the exploitation of farmers by traders in a liberalized market and dwindled
the little benefits further (Masuko, 1999).
Farmers were buying agricultural
inputs such as seeds, fertilizers and farming equipments at cheaper prices,
until ESAP liberalized trade and allowed traders to charge exorbitant prices
for these inputs (Oxfarm, 1995). They therefore could not cope with the higher
prices, especially considering that they had other household financial
obligations such as paying educational fees for their children (Mwanza, 1999).
To try and cope, small-scale farmers had to cut down their expenditure on
inputs (ibid). The obvious result was low yield, particularly for people in
areas that received low rainfall and characterized by poorer soils. Farmers
also reported that during ESAP, a lot of acquisitions had become taxable,
including cattle and other domestic animals (Rukuni& Eicher, 1994). People
were also required to pay dip tank chemicals and cattle treatment, although the
frequency of dipping cattle had been reduced from weekly to fortnightly
(Munhamo, 1998).
The costs of cattle tax and dip tank
levies combined with inputs costs further dig deep into already shrunken
pockets of poor people. Removal of farming subsidies has resulted in the cost
of basic goods and services escalating thereby affecting food availability at
household level (Makamure, 1996). The phase-out of subsidies should have been
done in a cautious manner. An enabling environment should be created through
among others, speeding up the surveying and developing of growth points, giving
incentives to business people to start small scale, labor intensive input and
processing industries at growth points (Government of Zimbabwe, 1997).
To add on, agricultural exports
became increasingly unbalanced and earnings became unpredictable as by 1992 the
contribution of the total agricultural export earnings of tobacco alone had increased
to 78% (Muchena, 1995). The LSCF sector gained most from the government
stimulated export drive under ESAP.
Conclusion, Structural Adjustment
involved reforms to macroeconomic and trade policies, which were designed,
among other objectives, to improve price incentives for producers of tradables.
As the output mix of the agricultural sector including many smallholder
sub-sectors, has a higher share of tradables and near-tradables than most other
key economic sectors and a vigorous agricultural supply response had been
anticipated via the improved terms of trade brought about by
liberalization.Likewise, by lifting restrictions on private sector entry into
the marketing of agricultural produce, it was hoped that there would be a
strong private sector response in supplying inputs and in purchasing, storing,
processing and (where appropriate) exporting produce. Additionally, it was
thought that parallel financial sector reforms (encompassing monetary
management at the macro-level, through banking sector reforms down to the
commercialization or privatization of State-supported agricultural finance
organizations) would catalyze the other elements of structural adjustment by
channeling funds to emerging opportunities for profitable farming and trade.
Although Zimbabwe has gone very far
in the area of liberalization of agricultural markets, it has realized modest
success in smallholder and communal agriculture. In many developed economies,
agricultural markets are still controlled and subsidized, with their farmers
continuing to receive subsidies and other support. The World Bank however,
expected farmers to adapt to an unsubsidized market-led environment in an
unfairly short time period. Small holder agriculture has therefore failed to
provide a route out of poverty for the majority. The role of the State in a
liberalized agricultural marketing system and efficiently functioning
institutions is critical to the success of the various measures. Programs to
enhance smallholder agricultural productivity and relieving poverty in the
communal areas need long-term government and donor support.
REFERENCES
Berman B. W. & Carter, S. (1997): Structural
Adjustment and Trade Liberalization –its Effect on Marketing.
Commercial Farmers Union (1999): Agricultural Overview.
Cotton Company of Zimbabwe (1997): Annual Report
Cotton Company of Zimbabwe (1999): Annual Report Industry
Review
COTTCO (1999): Review of COTTCO’s Success Story.
Dorward, A. J.
(1999): Smallholder Cash Crop Production under C. Poultry on Market
Liberalization.
Friedrich, E. S. (1999:24): Lobbying and Advocacy for
Smallholder; Seminar Proceedings, Economic Advocacy Project.
Friedrich, E. S. (1997:12): Land Reforms in the SADC
Region–Current Situation & Perspectives, Seminar Proceedings, Economic
Advocacy Project.
Friedrich, E. S. (1997):Post-Lome IV Opportunities for
SADC Agriculture, Seminar Proceedings (Economic Advocacy Project, Harare,
Zimbabwe.
Friedrich, E. S. (1998:16): The Land Reform Challenge:
Zimbabwe Economics Society; an Economic and Social Perspective (Volume 2),
Seminar Proceedings, Economic Advocacy Project.
Government of Zimbabwe (1997/98): Policy Statement for
the Agricultural Marketing Year.
Government of Zimbabwe (1995): Zimbabwe’s Agricultural
Policy Framework, Ministry of Agriculture.
Leather Institute of Zimbabwe (1999): the Zimbabwean Beef
Industry Review, Department of Research and Specialist Services (Cold
Storage Company Limited).
Makamure, J. (1996): Deregulation of Agricultural Markets,
ZNCC
Masanzu F. M., e t al (1998): Working Paper No. 22, Economic
Advocacy Project.
Masuko, L. (1999): Economic Policy Reforms and Meso-Scale
Rural Market Changes in Zimbabwe (The Case of Shamva District).
Muchena, S.C. (1995): Options for Diversification within
Small holder farming for sustainable food security.
Mukora, C. & Friedrich, E. S. (1997): An Evaluation
of the Crop Pack Program, Working Paper No. 18, Economic Advocacy Project.
Munhamo, C. (1998): Reaping the Whirlwind, Economic
Liberalization and Food Security in Zimbabwe.
Mwanza, A. (1999): Social Policy in an Economy under
Stress; the Case of Zimbabwe, SAPES.
Nyagura, C. e t al (1998): Land Reform in Zimbabwe:
Farmers’ and Academics’ View Points, Working Paper No. 23, Economic Advocacy
Project.
Oxfam Poverty Report (1995): Privatization
COTTCO (1999): Review
of COTTCO’s Success Story.
Rukuni, M., & Eicher, C. K. (1994): Zimbabwe’s
Agricultural Revolution, University of Zimbabwe Publications.
Silveira House (1996): Social Series No 15, Poverty in
the ESAP Era, poverty studies in Zimbabwe mining, commercial and communal
farming areas.
Structural Adjustment Participatory Review Initiative
(SAPRI) (1999): Participatory Terms of Reference for Uganda Country Studies
Whiteside, M. (1997): Living Farms, Encouraging
Sustainable Smallholders in Southern Africa.
ZIMACE Traders (1999)
Zimbabwe Farmers Union (1998/99): Planning
Document for Agriculture Season
No comments:
Post a Comment